🗊Презентация Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy

Нажмите для полного просмотра!
Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №1Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №2Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №3Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №4Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №5Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №6Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №7Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №8Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №9Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №10Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №11Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №12Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №13Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №14Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №15Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №16Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №17Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №18Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №19Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №20Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №21Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №22Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №23Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №24Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №25Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №26Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №27Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №28Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №29Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №30Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №31Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №32

Вы можете ознакомиться и скачать презентацию на тему Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy. Доклад-сообщение содержит 32 слайдов. Презентации для любого класса можно скачать бесплатно. Если материал и наш сайт презентаций Mypresentation Вам понравились – поделитесь им с друзьями с помощью социальных кнопок и добавьте в закладки в своем браузере.

Слайды и текст этой презентации


Слайд 1





ECONOMIC GROWTH II: 
ECONOMIC GROWTH II: 
TECHNOLOGY, EMPIRICS, AND POLICY
Описание слайда:
ECONOMIC GROWTH II: ECONOMIC GROWTH II: TECHNOLOGY, EMPIRICS, AND POLICY

Слайд 2








9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model 
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics 
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
9-5 Conclusion
Описание слайда:
9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model 9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics 9-3 Policies to Promote Growth 9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory 9-5 Conclusion

Слайд 3






Our analysis of the forces governing long-run growth
Tasks:
1st  to make the Solow model more general and realistic.
The Solow model does not explain technological progress but, instead, takes it as exogenously.
2nd to move from theory to empirics.
The Solow model can shed much light on international growth experiences, but it is far from the last word on the subject.
3d to examine how a nation’s public policies can infl uence the level and growth of its citizens’ standard of living. 
Should our society save more or less? 
How can policy infl uence the rate of saving?
Are there some types of investment that policy should especially encourage? 
What institutions ensure that the economy’s resources are put to their best use? 
How can policy increase the rate of TLP? 
The Solow growth model provides the theoretical framework within which we consider these policy issues.
4th to consider what the Solow model leaves out. 
We examine a new set of theories, called endogenous growth theories, which help to explain the TLP that the Solow model takes as exogenous.
Описание слайда:
Our analysis of the forces governing long-run growth Tasks: 1st to make the Solow model more general and realistic. The Solow model does not explain technological progress but, instead, takes it as exogenously. 2nd to move from theory to empirics. The Solow model can shed much light on international growth experiences, but it is far from the last word on the subject. 3d to examine how a nation’s public policies can infl uence the level and growth of its citizens’ standard of living. Should our society save more or less? How can policy infl uence the rate of saving? Are there some types of investment that policy should especially encourage? What institutions ensure that the economy’s resources are put to their best use? How can policy increase the rate of TLP? The Solow growth model provides the theoretical framework within which we consider these policy issues. 4th to consider what the Solow model leaves out. We examine a new set of theories, called endogenous growth theories, which help to explain the TLP that the Solow model takes as exogenous.

Слайд 4





9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model
where E is the efficiency of labor.
the available technology improves, the efficiency of labor rises, and each hour of work contributes more to the production of goods and services. 
The term L * E can be interpreted as measuring the effective number of workers.
L measures the number of workers in the labor force,
L × E measures both the workers and the technology with which the typical worker comes equipped. 
The simplest assumption about TLP is that it causes the E to grow at some constant rate g. 
For example, if g = 0.02,
then each unit of labor becomes 2%  more efficient each year: output increases as if the labor force had increased by 2 percent more than it really did.
This form of TLP is called labor augmenting, and  g is called the rate of labor-augmenting T/LP. 
The  L is growing at n, and 
the E is growing at g, 
the L × E is growing at  n + g.
90
Описание слайда:
9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model where E is the efficiency of labor. the available technology improves, the efficiency of labor rises, and each hour of work contributes more to the production of goods and services. The term L * E can be interpreted as measuring the effective number of workers. L measures the number of workers in the labor force, L × E measures both the workers and the technology with which the typical worker comes equipped. The simplest assumption about TLP is that it causes the E to grow at some constant rate g. For example, if g = 0.02, then each unit of labor becomes 2% more efficient each year: output increases as if the labor force had increased by 2 percent more than it really did. This form of TLP is called labor augmenting, and g is called the rate of labor-augmenting T/LP. The L is growing at n, and the E is growing at g, the L × E is growing at n + g. 90

Слайд 5





9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model
Because T/LP is modeled here as labor augmenting, it fits into the model in much the same way as population growth. 
When there was no T/LP, we analyzed the economy in terms of quantities per worker;
We now let 
k = K/(L × E) stand for capital per effective worker 
y = Y/(L × E) stand for output per effective worker. 
=>  y = f(k).
Δk = sf(k) − (δ + n + g)k.
to keep k constant, 
δk is needed to replace depreciating capital, 
nk is needed to provide capital for new workers,
gk is needed to provide capital for the new “effective workers” created by T/LP.
Описание слайда:
9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model Because T/LP is modeled here as labor augmenting, it fits into the model in much the same way as population growth. When there was no T/LP, we analyzed the economy in terms of quantities per worker; We now let k = K/(L × E) stand for capital per effective worker y = Y/(L × E) stand for output per effective worker. => y = f(k). Δk = sf(k) − (δ + n + g)k. to keep k constant, δk is needed to replace depreciating capital, nk is needed to provide capital for new workers, gk is needed to provide capital for the new “effective workers” created by T/LP.

Слайд 6





9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model
The Efficiency of Labor 
The Steady State With Technological Progress 
The Effects of Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model The Efficiency of Labor The Steady State With Technological Progress The Effects of Technological Progress

Слайд 7





9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model
The Efficiency of Labor 
The Steady State With Technological Progress 
The Effects of Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-1 Technological Progress in the Solow Model The Efficiency of Labor The Steady State With Technological Progress The Effects of Technological Progress

Слайд 8





9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics
Balanced Growth 
Convergence
Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency
Описание слайда:
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics Balanced Growth Convergence Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency

Слайд 9





9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics
Balanced Growth 
Convergence
Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency
Описание слайда:
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics Balanced Growth Convergence Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency

Слайд 10





9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics
Balanced Growth 
Convergence
Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency
Описание слайда:
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics Balanced Growth Convergence Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency

Слайд 11





9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics
Balanced Growth 
Convergence
Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency
Описание слайда:
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics Balanced Growth Convergence Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency

Слайд 12





9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics
Balanced Growth 
Convergence
Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency
Описание слайда:
9-2 From Growth Theory to Growth Empirics Balanced Growth Convergence Factor Accumulation Versus Production Efficiency

Слайд 13





Is Free Trade Good for Economic Growth?
At least since Adam Smith, economists have advocated free trade as a policy that
promotes national prosperity.
Today, economists make the case with greater rigor, relying on David Ricardo’s
theory of comparative advantage as well as more modern theories of international
trade. 
	According to these theories, a nation open to trade can achieve
greater production efficiency and a higher standard of living by specializing in
those goods for which it has a comparative advantage.
 1 approach is to look at international data to see if countries that are 
open to trade typically enjoy greater prosperity. The evidence shows that they do.
2nd approach is to look at what happens when 
closed economies remove their trade restrictions. Once again, Smith’s hypothesis fares well.
3rd approach to measuring the impact of trade on growth, proposed by economists Jeffrey Frankel and David Romer, is to look at 
the impact of geography. Some countries trade less simply because they are geographically disadvantaged.
Описание слайда:
Is Free Trade Good for Economic Growth? At least since Adam Smith, economists have advocated free trade as a policy that promotes national prosperity. Today, economists make the case with greater rigor, relying on David Ricardo’s theory of comparative advantage as well as more modern theories of international trade. According to these theories, a nation open to trade can achieve greater production efficiency and a higher standard of living by specializing in those goods for which it has a comparative advantage. 1 approach is to look at international data to see if countries that are open to trade typically enjoy greater prosperity. The evidence shows that they do. 2nd approach is to look at what happens when closed economies remove their trade restrictions. Once again, Smith’s hypothesis fares well. 3rd approach to measuring the impact of trade on growth, proposed by economists Jeffrey Frankel and David Romer, is to look at the impact of geography. Some countries trade less simply because they are geographically disadvantaged.

Слайд 14





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
The  U.S. economy is at, above, or below the GR SS?
we need to compare MPK − δ with the growth rate of total output (n + g). 
At the GR SS: MPK − δ = n + g. 
If the economy is operating with < capital than in the GRSS, then 
Diminishing MPC tells us that MPK − δ > n + g. →
↑ing the s => to
↑ capital accumulation and economic growth 
a SS with ↑er K 
(although K will be ↓er for part of the transition to the new SS). 
If the economy has > capital than in the GR SS, then 
MPK − δ < n + g. → capital accumulation is excessive: 
reducing the s => to
↑er K both immediately and in the long run.
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth The U.S. economy is at, above, or below the GR SS? we need to compare MPK − δ with the growth rate of total output (n + g). At the GR SS: MPK − δ = n + g. If the economy is operating with < capital than in the GRSS, then Diminishing MPC tells us that MPK − δ > n + g. → ↑ing the s => to ↑ capital accumulation and economic growth a SS with ↑er K (although K will be ↓er for part of the transition to the new SS). If the economy has > capital than in the GR SS, then MPK − δ < n + g. → capital accumulation is excessive: reducing the s => to ↑er K both immediately and in the long run.

Слайд 15





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Example: 
Real GDP in the U.S. grows an average of 3% per year
                                                                                     n + g = 0.03. 
We can estimate the net MPC from:
1. The CS is about 2.5 times one year’s GDP.       k = 2.5y
2. Depreciation of capital is about 10% of GDP.  δk = 0.1y
3. Capital income is about 30% of GDP.                MPK × k = 0.3y 
We solve for the rate of depreciation  by dividing equation 2 by equation 1: 
δk/k = (0.1y)/(2.5y);   δ= 0.04.
And we solve for the MPK by dividing equation 3 by equation 1: 
(MPK × k)/k = (0.3y)/(2.5y);  MPK = 0.12.
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Example: Real GDP in the U.S. grows an average of 3% per year n + g = 0.03. We can estimate the net MPC from: 1. The CS is about 2.5 times one year’s GDP. k = 2.5y 2. Depreciation of capital is about 10% of GDP. δk = 0.1y 3. Capital income is about 30% of GDP. MPK × k = 0.3y We solve for the rate of depreciation by dividing equation 2 by equation 1: δk/k = (0.1y)/(2.5y); δ= 0.04. And we solve for the MPK by dividing equation 3 by equation 1: (MPK × k)/k = (0.3y)/(2.5y); MPK = 0.12.

Слайд 16





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 17





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 18





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 19





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 20





4 Industrial Policy in Practice 
Policymakers and economists have long debated whether the government should
promote certain industries and fi rms because they are strategically important
for the economy. In the United States, the debate goes back over two centuries.
Alexander Hamilton, the fi rst U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, favored tariffs on
certain imports to encourage the development of domestic manufacturing.
The Tariff of 1789 was the second act passed by the new federal government.
The tariff helped manufacturers, but it hurt farmers, who had to pay more for
foreign-made products. Because the North was home to most of the manufacturers,
while the South had more farmers, the tariff was one source of the
regional tensions that eventually led to the Civil War.
Advocates of a signifi cant government role in promoting technology can point
to some recent successes. For example, the precursor of the modern Internet is
a system called Arpanet, which was established by an arm of the U.S. Department
of Defense as a way for information to fl ow among military installations.
There is little doubt that the Internet has been associated with large advances in
productivity and that the government had a hand in its creation. According to
proponents of industrial policy, this example illustrates how the government can
help jump-start an emerging technology.
Yet governments can also make mistakes when they try to supplant private
business decisions. Japan’s Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI)
is sometimes viewed as a successful practitioner of industrial policy, but it once
tried to stop Honda from expanding its business from motorcycles to automobiles.
MITI thought that the nation already had enough car manufacturers.
Fortunately, the government lost this battle, and Honda turned into one of the
world’s largest and most profi table car companies. Soichiro Honda, the company’s
founder, once said, “Probably I would have been even more successful had we
not had MITI.”
Over the past several years, government policy has aimed to promote “green
technologies.” In particular, the U.S. federal government has subsidized the production
of energy in ways that yield lower carbon emissions, which are thought
to contribute to global climate change. It is too early to judge the long-run success
of this policy, but there have been some short-run embarrassments. In 2011,
a manufacturer of solar panels called Solyndra declared bankruptcy two years
after the federal government granted it a $535 million loan guarantee. Moreover,
there were allegations that the decision to grant the loan guarantee had been
politically motivated rather than based on an objective evaluation of Solyndra’s
business plan. As this book was going to press, the Solyndra case was under investigation
by congressional committees and the FBI.
The debate over industrial policy will surely continue in the years to come.
The fi nal judgment about this kind of government intervention in the market
requires evaluating both the effi ciency of unfettered markets and the ability of
governmental institutions to identify technologies worthy of support. ■
Описание слайда:
4 Industrial Policy in Practice Policymakers and economists have long debated whether the government should promote certain industries and fi rms because they are strategically important for the economy. In the United States, the debate goes back over two centuries. Alexander Hamilton, the fi rst U.S. Secretary of the Treasury, favored tariffs on certain imports to encourage the development of domestic manufacturing. The Tariff of 1789 was the second act passed by the new federal government. The tariff helped manufacturers, but it hurt farmers, who had to pay more for foreign-made products. Because the North was home to most of the manufacturers, while the South had more farmers, the tariff was one source of the regional tensions that eventually led to the Civil War. Advocates of a signifi cant government role in promoting technology can point to some recent successes. For example, the precursor of the modern Internet is a system called Arpanet, which was established by an arm of the U.S. Department of Defense as a way for information to fl ow among military installations. There is little doubt that the Internet has been associated with large advances in productivity and that the government had a hand in its creation. According to proponents of industrial policy, this example illustrates how the government can help jump-start an emerging technology. Yet governments can also make mistakes when they try to supplant private business decisions. Japan’s Ministry of International Trade and Industry (MITI) is sometimes viewed as a successful practitioner of industrial policy, but it once tried to stop Honda from expanding its business from motorcycles to automobiles. MITI thought that the nation already had enough car manufacturers. Fortunately, the government lost this battle, and Honda turned into one of the world’s largest and most profi table car companies. Soichiro Honda, the company’s founder, once said, “Probably I would have been even more successful had we not had MITI.” Over the past several years, government policy has aimed to promote “green technologies.” In particular, the U.S. federal government has subsidized the production of energy in ways that yield lower carbon emissions, which are thought to contribute to global climate change. It is too early to judge the long-run success of this policy, but there have been some short-run embarrassments. In 2011, a manufacturer of solar panels called Solyndra declared bankruptcy two years after the federal government granted it a $535 million loan guarantee. Moreover, there were allegations that the decision to grant the loan guarantee had been politically motivated rather than based on an objective evaluation of Solyndra’s business plan. As this book was going to press, the Solyndra case was under investigation by congressional committees and the FBI. The debate over industrial policy will surely continue in the years to come. The fi nal judgment about this kind of government intervention in the market requires evaluating both the effi ciency of unfettered markets and the ability of governmental institutions to identify technologies worthy of support. ■

Слайд 21





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 22





The Colonial Origins of Modern Institutions
International data show a remarkable correlation between latitude and economic
prosperity: nations closer to the equator typically have lower levels of income
per person than nations farther from the equator. This fact is true in both the
northern and southern hemispheres.
What explains the correlation? Some economists have suggested that the
tropical climates near the equator have a direct negative impact on productivity.
In the heat of the tropics, agriculture is more diffi cult, and disease is more prevalent.
This makes the production of goods and services more diffi cult.
Although the direct impact of geography is one reason tropical nations tend
to be poor, it is not the whole story. Research by Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson,
and James Robinson has suggested an indirect mechanism—the impact of
geography on institutions. Here is their explanation, presented in several steps:
1. In the seventeenth, eighteenth, and nineteenth centuries, tropical climates
presented European settlers with an increased risk of disease, especially
malaria and yellow fever. As a result, when Europeans were colonizing much
of the rest of the world, they avoided settling in tropical areas, such as most of
Africa and Central America. The European settlers preferred areas with more
moderate climates and better health conditions, such as the regions that are
now the United States, Canada, and New Zealand.
2. In those areas where Europeans settled in large numbers, the settlers established
European-like institutions that protected individual property rights
and limited the power of government. By contrast, in tropical climates, the
colonial powers often set up “extractive” institutions, including authoritarian
governments, so they could take advantage of the area’s natural resources.
These institutions enriched the colonizers, but they did little to foster economic
growth.
3. Although the era of colonial rule is now long over, the early institutions that
the European colonizers established are strongly correlated with the modern
institutions in the former colonies. In tropical nations, where the colonial
powers set up extractive institutions, there is typically less protection of property
rights even today. When the colonizers left, the extractive institutions
remained and were simply taken over by new ruling elites.
4. The quality of institutions is a key determinant of economic performance.
Where property rights are well protected, people have more incentive to
make the investments that lead to economic growth. Where property rights
are less respected, as is typically the case in tropical nations, investment and
growth tend to lag behind.
This research suggests that much of the international variation in living standards
that we observe today is a result of the long reach of history.
Описание слайда:
The Colonial Origins of Modern Institutions International data show a remarkable correlation between latitude and economic prosperity: nations closer to the equator typically have lower levels of income per person than nations farther from the equator. This fact is true in both the northern and southern hemispheres. What explains the correlation? Some economists have suggested that the tropical climates near the equator have a direct negative impact on productivity. In the heat of the tropics, agriculture is more diffi cult, and disease is more prevalent. This makes the production of goods and services more diffi cult. Although the direct impact of geography is one reason tropical nations tend to be poor, it is not the whole story. Research by Daron Acemoglu, Simon Johnson, and James Robinson has suggested an indirect mechanism—the impact of geography on institutions. Here is their explanation, presented in several steps: 1. In the seventeenth, eighteenth, and nineteenth centuries, tropical climates presented European settlers with an increased risk of disease, especially malaria and yellow fever. As a result, when Europeans were colonizing much of the rest of the world, they avoided settling in tropical areas, such as most of Africa and Central America. The European settlers preferred areas with more moderate climates and better health conditions, such as the regions that are now the United States, Canada, and New Zealand. 2. In those areas where Europeans settled in large numbers, the settlers established European-like institutions that protected individual property rights and limited the power of government. By contrast, in tropical climates, the colonial powers often set up “extractive” institutions, including authoritarian governments, so they could take advantage of the area’s natural resources. These institutions enriched the colonizers, but they did little to foster economic growth. 3. Although the era of colonial rule is now long over, the early institutions that the European colonizers established are strongly correlated with the modern institutions in the former colonies. In tropical nations, where the colonial powers set up extractive institutions, there is typically less protection of property rights even today. When the colonizers left, the extractive institutions remained and were simply taken over by new ruling elites. 4. The quality of institutions is a key determinant of economic performance. Where property rights are well protected, people have more incentive to make the investments that lead to economic growth. Where property rights are less respected, as is typically the case in tropical nations, investment and growth tend to lag behind. This research suggests that much of the international variation in living standards that we observe today is a result of the long reach of history.

Слайд 23





9-3 Policies to Promote Growth
Evaluating the Rate of Saving
Changing the Rate of Saving
Allocating the Economy’s Investment
Establishing the Right Institutions
Encouraging Technological Progress
Описание слайда:
9-3 Policies to Promote Growth Evaluating the Rate of Saving Changing the Rate of Saving Allocating the Economy’s Investment Establishing the Right Institutions Encouraging Technological Progress

Слайд 24





The Worldwide Slowdown in Economic Growth
Описание слайда:
The Worldwide Slowdown in Economic Growth

Слайд 25





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
Endogenous Growth Theory reject the Solow model’s assumption of exogenous technological change.
Y = AK,
Y is output,  K is the capital stock, A is a constant measuring the amount of Y produced for each unit of K.
PF does not exhibit the property of diminishing returns to capital.
K = sY − Kδ.
Y/Y = K/K = sA − δ. 
sA > δ, the economy’s income grows forever, even without the assumption of exogenous T/LP.
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory Endogenous Growth Theory reject the Solow model’s assumption of exogenous technological change. Y = AK, Y is output, K is the capital stock, A is a constant measuring the amount of Y produced for each unit of K. PF does not exhibit the property of diminishing returns to capital. K = sY − Kδ. Y/Y = K/K = sA − δ. sA > δ, the economy’s income grows forever, even without the assumption of exogenous T/LP.

Слайд 26





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
Y = F[K, (1 − u)LE] (PF in manufacturing firms),
E = g(u)E (PF in research universities),
K = sY − K (capital accumulation),
u is the fraction of the labor force in universities  
1 − u is the fraction in manufacturing, 
E is the stock of knowledge (efficiency of labor), 
g is a function that shows how the growth in knowledge ~ on the fraction of the labor force in universities. 
 Assumtion:
The PF for the MF have constant returns to scale.
This model is a cousin of the Y = AK model. 
This economy exhibits constant returns to capital, as long as capital is broadly defined to include knowledge. Persistent growth arises endogenously because the creation of knowledge in universities never slows down.
This model is also a cousin of the Solow growth model. 
If u is held constant, then the E grows at the constant rate g(u). This result of constant growth in the E of labor at rate g is precisely the assumption made in the Solow model with T/LP. 
For any given value of u, this endogenous growth model works just like the Solow model.
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory Y = F[K, (1 − u)LE] (PF in manufacturing firms), E = g(u)E (PF in research universities), K = sY − K (capital accumulation), u is the fraction of the labor force in universities 1 − u is the fraction in manufacturing, E is the stock of knowledge (efficiency of labor), g is a function that shows how the growth in knowledge ~ on the fraction of the labor force in universities. Assumtion: The PF for the MF have constant returns to scale. This model is a cousin of the Y = AK model. This economy exhibits constant returns to capital, as long as capital is broadly defined to include knowledge. Persistent growth arises endogenously because the creation of knowledge in universities never slows down. This model is also a cousin of the Solow growth model. If u is held constant, then the E grows at the constant rate g(u). This result of constant growth in the E of labor at rate g is precisely the assumption made in the Solow model with T/LP. For any given value of u, this endogenous growth model works just like the Solow model.

Слайд 27





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
2 key decision variables in this model. 
As in the Solow model,
s determines the SS stock of K. 
u determines the growth in the stock of knowledge. 
s & u affect the level of income
u affects the SS growth rate of income. 
Thus, this model of endogenous growth takes a small step in the direction of showing 
which societal decisions determine the rate of technological change.
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory 2 key decision variables in this model. As in the Solow model, s determines the SS stock of K. u determines the growth in the stock of knowledge. s & u affect the level of income u affects the SS growth rate of income. Thus, this model of endogenous growth takes a small step in the direction of showing which societal decisions determine the rate of technological change.

Слайд 28





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
1. knowledge is largely a public goodю, much research is done in firms that are driven by the profit motive. 
2. research is profitable because 
innovations give firms temporary monopolies,
of the patent system
there is an advantage to being the first firm on the market with a new product. 
3. when one firm innovates, other firms build on that innovation to produce the next generation of innovations.
These (essentially microeconomic) facts are not easily connected with the (essentially macroeconomic) growth models we have discussed so far.
Some endogenous growth models try to incorporate these facts about
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory 1. knowledge is largely a public goodю, much research is done in firms that are driven by the profit motive. 2. research is profitable because innovations give firms temporary monopolies, of the patent system there is an advantage to being the first firm on the market with a new product. 3. when one firm innovates, other firms build on that innovation to produce the next generation of innovations. These (essentially microeconomic) facts are not easily connected with the (essentially macroeconomic) growth models we have discussed so far. Some endogenous growth models try to incorporate these facts about

Слайд 29





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
The Basic Model
A Two-Sector Model
The Microeconomics of Research and Development
The Process of Creative Destruction
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory The Basic Model A Two-Sector Model The Microeconomics of Research and Development The Process of Creative Destruction

Слайд 30





9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory
In his 1942 book Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, economist Joseph Schumpeter suggested that economic progress comes through a process of creative destruction.
According to Schumpeter, the driving force behind progress is the entrepreneur with an idea for a new product, a new way to produce an old product, or some other innovation.
Examples:
In England in the early 19 century, an important innovation was the invention and spread of machines that could produce textiles using unskilled workers at low cost.
Term “Luddite” refers to anyone who opposes technological progress.
A more recent example of creative destruction involves the retailing giant Walmart.
Описание слайда:
9-4 Beyond the Solow Model: Endogenous Growth Theory In his 1942 book Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy, economist Joseph Schumpeter suggested that economic progress comes through a process of creative destruction. According to Schumpeter, the driving force behind progress is the entrepreneur with an idea for a new product, a new way to produce an old product, or some other innovation. Examples: In England in the early 19 century, an important innovation was the invention and spread of machines that could produce textiles using unskilled workers at low cost. Term “Luddite” refers to anyone who opposes technological progress. A more recent example of creative destruction involves the retailing giant Walmart.

Слайд 31





9-5 Conclusion
Long-run economic growth is the single most important determinant of the economic well-being of a nation’s citizens. 
The Solow growth model and the more recent endogenous growth models show how 	
saving, 
population growth, and 
technological progress 
interact in determining the level and growth of a nation’s standard of living.
Описание слайда:
9-5 Conclusion Long-run economic growth is the single most important determinant of the economic well-being of a nation’s citizens. The Solow growth model and the more recent endogenous growth models show how saving, population growth, and technological progress interact in determining the level and growth of a nation’s standard of living.

Слайд 32


Economic growth. Technology, empirics, and policy, слайд №32
Описание слайда:



Похожие презентации
Mypresentation.ru
Загрузить презентацию